Raphael Bostic
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
September 3, 2025
Key Points
Understanding a $30 trillion economy, a chore at any time, is especially complicated as we proceed further into 2025.
Uncertainty abounds. The full implications of trade policy remain unclear. It's not known how proposed federal deregulation and tax changes will manifest, nor the extent to which those shifts offset one another or tariff-related cost increases. Geopolitical uncertainties remain relevant.
Complexity confronts not just policy makers like me. At nearly every stop in my travels across the Southeast, I poll audiences on who feels confident in their business forecast for the next six months. In recent weeks, nary a hand has gone up.
For me, the job is calibrating monetary policy, which requires a clear read on the state of the US economy. Amid deep and wide complexity, I find that focusing on fundamentals helps to frame my thinking. So, before I detail my current economic and policy outlook, I will outline questions and tenets that underpin my policymaking process. These first principles, if you will, keep me locked in on the core mission.
First, how is the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) faring relative to the goals Congress has assigned us—achieving price stability and sustained maximum employment? How do I think the economy will evolve with respect to the two core objectives?
Committee participants must digest and analyze layer upon layer of data, anecdotal and survey feedback, research, the products of predictive models, and other material. Ultimately, though, the decision comes down to which is the greater risk: rising inflation or a deteriorating labor market. Of course, it's often not clear cut; the relative risks fall on a spectrum. Therefore, along with 18 other FOMC participants, I must determine where I think we are on that spectrum of risk.
Services prices still high, goods prices rising
To reach that judgment, I size up economic conditions.
Start with inflation. The Committee's preferred gauge, the personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price index, has run above our 2 percent target for four years. After substantial declines in the inflation rate starting in late 2022, progress essentially stalled in the fall of last year.
An important culprit: prices of core services—those other than energy services. As chart 1 shows, core services prices have lingered above prepandemic averages, preventing a fulsome return to the Committee's overall inflation target. To add to this, goods prices are also now increasing, a risk related in part to tariffs. For context, tariff rates across all US imports now average about 15 to 18 percent, compared to roughly 2 percent at the end of 2024.
The puzzle I'm grappling with is whether those inflationary effects of tariffs will quickly pass or prove more persistent. Even among FOMC participants, opinions on that question vary. I continue to believe that the effects of tariffs on consumer prices won't fade fast, and in fact will not fully materialize for some months. My view is based on input from business leaders and extensive research.
For example, a team of Atlanta Fed economists dug into results from our battery of surveys of business leaders and found that on net, their expectations of their own future prices have increased meaningfully since the end of 2024. It's not just firms directly affected by tariffs, either. Yes, the imposition of tariffs appears to be an important catalyst for the spike in price growth expectations. But the spillover onto firms that are not exposed to tariffs "raises the risk of a broad-based increase in inflation," the economists write.
I should add as a caveat that those results are probably sensitive to trade policy changes and therefore are best viewed as a risk to the inflation outlook should effective tariff rates remain largely unchanged from the first half of 2025. These findings are consistent with other research, including additional work from our team, the Yale Budget Lab, and economists connected to Harvard's Pricing Lab.
Our intelligence gathering team and I have heard similar messages from contacts in recent weeks. One, tariffs are indeed increasing costs. Two, most firms are absorbing those additional costs rather than boosting prices—so far. But three, most contacts may not have the capacity to eat higher costs much longer.
One nuance that has changed is that a majority of firms no longer expect to pass through to prices all the tariff cost increases. So, the ultimate impact on consumers might be more muted than it appeared a few months ago.
Lastly, on inflation, I'm concerned about the psyche of business leaders and households. If either or both begin to believe elevated price levels will stick for many months, then that belief can influence behavior in ways that lead to persistent inflation. As I noted, our surveys show business leaders have, in fact, raised their price expectations. Consumer inflation expectations, in contrast, have not risen too worryingly. But they do tend to be above the long-run target, clustered around 3 percent for one, three, and five years ahead, per the New York Fed.
Taken in total, these numbers give me pause. I will not be complacent and simply assume expectations will remain anchored and another inflation outbreak won't happen. My team and I will be monitoring developments regarding expectations quite closely.
One point that I don't think has been sufficiently emphasized is that, while the federal funds rate the Fed controls directly influences short-term rates, it's not a tectonic force that dictates all interest rates across the economy.
Just last year, for example, the Committee lowered the funds rate by a full percentage point—from a range of 5.25 to 5.5 percent to 4.25 to 4.5 percent over three meetings in September, November, and December. Over the same period, the average 30-year fixed mortgage rate actually increased. This is because yields on longer-duration assets, like 10-year Treasury securities and 30-year fixed-rate mortgages, are influenced by many factors other than monetary policy, such as investors' views of fiscal policy, national debt, and economic growth, among other factors.
My central point is that extraordinarily complex economic forces are at play. And it is important that policy makers, households, and businesses appreciate the depth and breadth of this complexity in making financial and economic decisions.
Labor market cooling, not collapsing
Turning to the other side of the dual mandate, the labor market has cooled sufficiently that the risks to the two mandated goals are likely coming closer to balanced. Monthly employment growth slowed significantly in the spring and summer, and it has for some time been overly concentrated in just a couple of sectors—notably health care (see chart 2). It is taking job seekers longer to find employment.
Nevertheless, for several reasons, I do not think it is unambiguously clear that the labor market is weakening materially relative to our mandated objectives. For one, we are not hearing alarming signals from business contacts. By and large, they are maintaining a "not-hiring-but-not firing" approach to payrolls. Second, labor supply has declined markedly, and so the unemployment rate has remained steady at just over 4 percent through the spring and summer (see chart 3). The US civilian labor force in July included 400,000 fewer people than it did in January, due to declines in net immigration and falling labor force participation. This sharp reduction in labor supply means that the number of jobs the economy needs to produce to break even—to keep the unemployment rate from rising—is much lower than we've seen in recent years. For context, estimates from our staff suggest that the breakeven level has declined from 125,000 to 150,000 new jobs a month to around 75,000 to 100,000 a month for 2025, and could continue to fall to a number below 50,000 per month in the next two years as the labor force is expected to grow at a slower pace.
For me, the takeaway on the labor market is this: If labor demand and labor supply are both slowing such that the unemployment rate is stable, then the labor market has not meaningfully weakened and, in fact, remains near full employment. In other words, we are still close to the Committee's maximum employment objective.
That said, I am not completely sanguine about employment. Signs of cooling bear scrutiny, as history tells us that the labor market can turn quickly and decisively. Former Fed economist Claudia Sahm developed a formula that has proven reliable—when the three-month moving average of the unemployment rate rises by 0.5 percentage points over the rate's 12-month low, then it keeps rising. Through July, the three-month moving average was just 0.2 percentage points above the 12-month low. So, again, that is not a shrieking alarm bell. But this bears watching.
Basic rules of formulating policy
In formulating a policy stance, it is my duty to determine whether the risk of not reaching our inflation goal is greater than, smaller than, or the same as the risk of not hitting the maximum employment goal. That formulation has become trickier in recent months, as the labor market slows even as inflation remains above target. Our economy is in a transition period. Unlike the majority of the past several years, when the risks to the inflation mandate were clearly greater than the risks to the employment mandate, risks to the employment mandate have increased such that the relative risks are more balanced.
Ultimately, my policy calculation comes down to the following: If the risk of not achieving price stability outweighs the risk of not achieving maximum employment, then the Committee probably wants restrictive policy that will curb inflation. On the other hand, if the greater risk is to the health of the labor market, then we may want policy to ease, or be mildly stimulative to support employment. If I conclude that the risks to both sides of the dual mandate are in fact equal, then we might want the federal funds rate to be at or near neutral, or a stance that is neither restrictive nor stimulative.
Today, I judge policy to be marginally restrictive. I believe that, while price stability remains the primary concern, the labor market is slowing enough that some easing in policy—probably on the order of 25 basis points—will be appropriate over the remainder of this year. That could change, depending on the trajectory of inflation and the evolution of employment markets in the coming months. I am and remain, after all, data dependent.
The value of the dual mandate
In this essay, I have attempted to be completely transparent in summarizing the policymaking approach of this FOMC participant. It is a delicate blend of science and art. That is especially the case because the Fed's dual mandate is unusual among major central banks around the world. If the Fed was like most central banks and pursued only price stability, then the Committee would be unconcerned with the employment implications of monetary policy. Lowering the federal funds rate in this environment would be out of the question.
The dual mandate, however, demands that we weigh difficult trade-offs. As I detailed in a recent speech, I believe the dual mandate serves the American public well. If you spend time following the Fed, you have undoubtedly heard Fed Chair Jerome Powell declare that price stability is necessary to achieve long-term labor market expansions that benefit all of our citizens. I agree, and I think that formulation succinctly captures the mutually reinforcing nature of the dual mandate.
I also believe that pursuing the two core objectives makes me a more well-rounded central banker. Cultivating conditions favorable to price stability and maximum employment requires a deep and nuanced appreciation for how economic activity actually happens—how products are produced and services delivered, how firms set prices, how and why hiring and investment occurs or does not, the mechanics of supply chains, financing, trends, strategies, and so on.
The FOMC has a statutory obligation to pursue two goals, and it's not always easy. But that's the mandate. And a mandate serves to focus one's energy even in times of great uncertainty, like the present.
A few reflections on our updated framework
In closing, I'll offer a couple of thoughts on the strategic framework review of our long-run policy strategy that the Committee just wrapped up. As Chair Powell described in an August speech, the revised framework emphasizes our commitment to "act forcefully to ensure that longer-term inflation expectations remain well anchored, to the benefit of both sides of our dual mandate." This is a component of the strategy that I feel is particularly salient, as I detailed in my aforementioned July speech.
The updated strategic framework also makes explicit the approach I described above that is guiding us today as we contemplate the stance and trajectory of policy. We consider the extent that each mandate dimension has departed from its stated goal as well as the potentially different time horizons it will take to achieve each goal.
I encourage you to read Chair Powell's August Jackson Hole speech for more on the revised strategic framework. Thank you for reading this message, and rest assured that the Committee will continue doing all we can to bring about both price stability and sustained maximum employment for the benefit of all Americans.
For event introductions, please use President Bostic's short bio
Dr. Raphael W. Bostic took office June 5, 2017, as the 15th president and chief executive officer of the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. He is responsible for all the Bank's activities, including monetary policy, bank supervision and regulation, and payment services. He serves on the Federal Open Market Committee, the monetary policymaking body of the Federal Reserve System.
From 2012 to 2017, Bostic was the Judith and John Bedrosian Chair in Governance and the Public Enterprise at the Sol Price School of Public Policy at the University of Southern California (USC).
He arrived at USC in 2001 and served as a professor in the School of Policy, Planning, and Development. His research has spanned many fields, including home ownership, housing finance, neighborhood change, and the role of institutions in shaping policy effectiveness. He was director of USC's master of real estate development degree program and was the founding director of the Casden Real Estate Economics Forecast.
Bostic also served USC's Lusk Center for Real Estate as the interim associate director from 2007 to 2009 and as the interim director from 2015 to 2016. From 2016 to 2017, he was the chair of the center's Governance, Management, and Policy Process Department.
From 2009 to 2012, Bostic was the assistant secretary for policy development and research at the US Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD). In that role, he was a principal adviser to the secretary on policy and research, helping the secretary and other principal staff make informed decisions on HUD policies and programs, as well as on budget and legislative proposals.
Bostic worked at the Federal Reserve Board of Governors from 1995 to 2001, first as an economist and then as a senior economist in the monetary and financial studies section, where his work on the Community Reinvestment Act earned him a special achievement award.
He is a member of Harvard University's Board of Overseers and serves on the boards of the Council for Economic Education, Urban Institute, and Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, among others. Locally, Bostic is involved with United Way of Greater Atlanta, the Metro Atlanta Chamber of Commerce, and the Woodruff Arts Center.
Bostic graduated from Harvard University in 1987 with a combined major in economics and psychology. He earned his doctorate in economics from Stanford University in 1995.
The Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta serves the Sixth Federal Reserve District, which covers Alabama, Florida, and Georgia, and parts of Louisiana, Mississippi, and Tennessee. The Bank has branches in Birmingham, Jacksonville, Miami, Nashville, and New Orleans.
Updated August 2025
Bostic, Raphael W. April 18, 2020. "Opinion: Fed's Working to Aid Economy, Post-Pandemic Recovery." Atlanta Journal-Constitution.
Bostic, R. and Johnson, M. January 15, 2020. "BankThink: How to keep community banks thriving." American Banker.
Boarnet, M. G.; Bostic, R. W.; Rodnyansky, S.; Burinskiy, E.; Eisenlohr, A.; Jamme, H.; and Santiago-Bartolomei, R. 2020. "Do High Income Households Reduce Driving More When Living near Rail Transit?" Transportation Research Part D: Transport and Environment 80.
Bostic, R. W.; Jakabovics, A.; Voith, R.; and Zielenbach, S. 2019. "Mixed-Income LIHTC Developments in Chicago: A First Look at Their Income Characteristics and Spillover Impacts." In What Works to Promote Inclusive, Equitable Mixed-Income Communities
, edited by Mark L. Joseph and Amy T. Khare, cluster #1, section A, no. 6.
Boarnet, M. G.; Bostic, R. W.; Burinskiy, E.; Rodnyansky, S.; and Prohofsky, A. 2018. "Gentrification near Rail Transit Areas: A Micro-Data Analysis of Moves into Los Angeles Metro Rail Station Areas. Research Reports, University of California National Center for Sustainable Transportation.
Bostic, R. W. and Molaison, D. Forthcoming. "Hurricane Katrina: Devastation, Possibilities and Prospects." In Economic and Risk Assessment of Hurricane Katrina, University of Southern California Center for Risk and Economic Analysis of Terrorism Events.
Bostic, R.; Kim, A.; and Valenzuela, A. 2016. "An Introduction to the Special Issue: Contesting the Streets 2: Vending and Public Space in Global Cities." Cityscape 18(1): 3–10.
Bostic, R. W. and Ellen, I. G. 2014. "Introduction: Special Issue on Housing Policy in the United States." Journal of Housing Economics 24: 1–3.
Bostic, R. 2014. "CDBG at 40: Opportunities and Obstacles." Housing Policy Debate 24(1): 297–302.
Bostic, R. W. 2014. "Resilient Economic Development: Challenges and Opportunities." In University of Illinois Chicago Urban Forum, edited by M. Pagano. University of Illinois Press.
Bostic, R. W. and McFarlane, A. 2013. "The Proposed Affirmatively Furthering Fair Housing Regulatory Impact Analysis." Cityscape: A Journal of Policy Development and Research 15(3): 257.
Bostic, R. W.; Thornton, R. L.; Rudd, E. C.; and Sternthal, M. J. 2012. "Health in All Policies: The Role of the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development and Present and Future Challenges." Health Affairs 31(9): online.
Graddy, E., with Bostic, R. W. 2010. "The Role of Private Agents in Affordable Housing Policy." Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 20, special issue: 81–99.
Bostic, R.; Gabriel, S.; and Painter, G. 2009. "Housing Wealth, Financial Wealth, and Consumption: New Evidence from Micro Data." Regional Science and Urban Economics 39(1): 79–89.
Bostic, R. W., with Engel, K.; McCoy, P.; A. Pennington-Cross; and Wachter, S. 2008. "State and Local Anti-Predatory Lending Laws: The Effect of Legal Enforcement Mechanisms." Journal of Economics and Business 60(1–2): 47–66.
An, X. and Bostic, R. W. 2008. "GSE Activity, FHA Feedback, and Implications for the Efficacy of the Affordable Housing Goals." Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 36(2): 207–31.
An, X.; Bostic, R. W.; Deng, Y.; and Gabriel, S. 2007. "GSE Loan Purchases, the FHA, and Housing Outcomes in Targeted, Low-Income Neighborhoods." In Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs, edited by G. Burtless and J.R. Pack. Brookings Institute Press.
Sloane, D. C., with Bostic, R. W. and Lewis, L. B. 2007. "The Neighborhood Dynamics of Hospitals as Land Owners." Lincoln Land Institute publication.
Bostic, R. W., with Longhofer, S. D. and Redfearn, C. 2007. "Land Leverage: Decomposing Home Price Dynamics." Real Estate Economics 35 (2): 183–208.
Bostic, R. W. and Prohofsky, A. 2006. "Enterprise Zones and Individual Welfare: A Case Study of California." Journal of Regional Science 46 (2): 175–203.
Bostic, R. W. and Gabriel, S. A. 2006. "Do the GSEs Matter to Low-Income Housing Markets? An Assessment of the Effects of GSE Loan Purchase Activity on California Housing Outcomes." Journal of Urban Economics 59: 458–75.
Black, H.; Bostic, R. W.; Robinson, B.; and Schweitzer, R. 2005. "Do CRA-Related Events Affect Shareholder Wealth? The Case of Bank Mergers." The Financial Review 40(4): 575–86.
Bostic, R. W. with Robinson, B. 2004. "Community Banking and Mortgage Credit Availability: The Impact of CRA Agreements." Journal of Banking and Finance 28: 3069–95.
Bostic, R. W., with Calem. P. S. and Wachter, S. M. 2004. "Hitting the Wall: Credit as an Impediment to Homeownership." In Building Assets, Building Credit: Creating Wealth in Low-Income Communities, edited by N. Retsinas and E. Belsky. Joint Center for Housing Studies and Brookings Institution Press.
Bostic, R. W., with Redfearn, C. 2004. "Book Review [The Color of Credit: Mortgage Discrimination, Research Methodology and Fair Lending Enforcement, by Stephen L. Ross and John Yinger]." Journal of Regional Science 44(1):162–65.
Bostic, R. W., with Aaronson, D.; Huck, P.; and Townsend, R. 2004. "Supplier Relationships and Small Business Use of Trade Credit." Journal of Urban Economics 55(1): 46–67.
Bostic, R. W., with Barakova, I.; Calem, P.; and Wachter, S. 2003. "Does Credit Quality Matter for Homeownership?" Journal of Housing Economics 12(4): 318–36.
Bostic, R. W. 2003. "A Test of Cultural Affinity in Home Mortgage Lending." Journal of Financial Services Research 23(2): 89–112.
Bostic, R., with Robinson, B. 2003. "Do CRA Agreements Increase Lending?" Real Estate Economics 31(1): 23–51.
Bostic, R. W., with Calem, P. S. 2003. "Privacy Restrictions and the Use of Data at Credit Repositories." In Credit Reporting Systems and the International Economy, edited by Margaret J. Miller. Boston: MIT Press.
Bostic, R. W., with Martin, R. 2003. "Black Homeowners as Gentrifying Force? Neighborhood Dynamics in the Context of Minority Homeownership." Urban Studies 40(12).
Bostic, R. W. 2002. "Equal Access to Credit." In 25 Years of Credit Research, edited by Mike Staten. Washington, DC: Georgetown University Press.
Bostic, R., with Canner, G. B. 2000. "Consolidation in Banking: How Recent Changes Have Affected the Provision of Banking Services." The Neighborworks Journal.
Bostic, R., with Avery, R. B. and Canner, G. B. 2000. "Highlights of a Survey of the Performance and Profitability of CRA-Related Lending." Housing America Update.
Bostic, R., with Avery, R. B. and Canner, G. B. 2000. "CRA Special Lending Programs." Federal Reserve Bulletin 86: 711–31.
Bostic, R., with Avery, R. B.; Calem, P. S.; and Canner, G. B. 2000. "Credit Scoring: Statistical Issues and Evidence from Credit Bureau Files." Real Estate Economics 28: 523–47.
Bostic, R., with Canner, G. B. 1998. "New Information on Small Business and Small Farm Lending: The 1996 CRA Data." Federal Reserve Bulletin 84(1): 1–21.
Bostic, R., with Avery, R. B. and Samolyk, K. A. 1998. "The Role of Personal Wealth in Small Business Finance." Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 1019–61.
Bostic, Raphael W. May 6, 2024. "How the Fed Goes Beyond the Data to Try to Make the Economy Work for Everyone." FedCommunities.
Bostic, R.; Bower, S.; Shy, O.; Wall, L.; and Washington, J. September 2020. "Digital Payments and the Path to Financial Inclusion." Promoting Safer Payments Innovation Series no. 20-1.
Raphael Bostic. "Quantitative Frightening?" macroblog. January 16, 2019.
Raphael Bostic. "What Does the Current Slope of the Yield Curve Tell Us?," macroblog. August 23, 2018.
Raphael Bostic. "Thoughts on a Long-Run Monetary Policy Framework" macroblog series:
"Framing the Question." March 26, 2018.
"Part 2: The Principle of Bounded Nominal Uncertainty." March 27, 2018.
"Part 3: An Example of Flexible Price-Level Targeting." March 28, 2018.
"Part 4: Flexible Price-Level Targeting in the Big Picture." April 2, 2018.
Raphael Bostic. "A Big-Picture Look at the Economy . " ECONversations. February 21, 2018.
Raphael Bostic. "'There's Still a Lot of Uncertainty': Atlanta Fed President Bostic Looks Back on 2024." January 7, 2025.
Raphael Bostic (interviewer) and Anthony Orlando. "'These Local Problems Do Have Some National Solutions': A Conversation about Inequality." February 27, 2020.
Raphael Bostic (interviewer) and James Fallows. "Wings over America: A Conversation with Author James Fallows." . January 2, 2020.
Raphael Bostic (interviewer) and Alessandro Acquisti. "Speaking Publicly on Privacy: A Conversation about Digital Privacy." April 2, 2019.
Raphael Bostic (interviewer) and Jerome Adams. "Health Is Wealth": A Conversation with the U.S. Surgeon General." January 3, 2019.
Raphael Bostic (interviewer) and Raj Chetty. "'A Kid Should Have a Fair Shot': A Discussion of Economic Mobility." October 22, 2018.
Raphael Bostic (interviewer) and David Lusk. "'It's a Really Dramatic Change': A Discussion of the Economics of Food." October 12, 2018.
Raphael Bostic. "'It's a Special Job': A Conversation with Atlanta Fed President Raphael Bostic." April 27, 2018.